Happy Faces of Productivity… The Invention of Capitalism: How a Self-Sufficient Peasantry was Whipped Into Industrial Wage Slaves.
“…everyone but an
idiot knows that the lower classes must be kept poor, or they will never be
industrious.”
—Arthur Young; 1771
Our popular economic wisdom says that capitalism equals freedom
and free societies, right? Well, if you ever suspected that the logic is full
of shit, then I’d recommend checking a book called The Invention of Capitalism,
written by an economic historian named Michael Perelmen, who’s been exiled to
Chico State, a redneck college in rural California, for his lack of freemarket
friendliness. Perelman has been putting his time in exile to damn good use,
digging deep into the works and correspondence of Adam Smith and his
contemporaries to write a history of the creation of capitalism that goes
beyond superficial The Wealth of Nations fairy tale and straight to the source,
allowing you to read the early capitalists, economists, philosophers, clergymen
and statesmen in their own words. And it ain’t pretty.
One thing that the historical record makes obviously clear
is that Adam Smith and his laissez-faire buddies were a bunch of closet-case
statists, who needed brutal government policies to whip the English peasantry
into a good capitalistic workforce willing to accept wage slavery.
Francis Hutcheson, from whom Adam Smith learned all about
the virtue of natural liberty, wrote: ”it is the one great design of civil laws
to strengthen by political sanctions the several laws of nature. … The populace
needs to be taught, and engaged by laws, into the best methods of managing
their own affairs and exercising mechanic art.”
Yep, despite what you might have learned, the transition to
a capitalistic society did not happen naturally or smoothly. See, English
peasants didn’t want to give up their rural communal lifestyle, leave their
land and go work for below-subsistence wages in shitty, dangerous factories
being set up by a new, rich class of landowning capitalists. And for good
reason, too. Using Adam Smith’s own estimates of factory wages being paid at
the time in Scotland, a factory-peasant would have to toil for more than three
days to buy a pair of commercially produced shoes. Or they could make their own
traditional brogues using their own leather in a matter of hours, and spend the
rest of the time getting wasted on ale. It’s really not much of a choice, is
it?
But in order for capitalism to work, capitalists needed a
pool of cheap, surplus labour. So what to do? Call in the National Guard!
Faced with a peasantry that didn’t feel like playing the
role of slave, philosophers, economists, politicians, moralists and leading
business figures began advocating for government action. Over time, they
enacted a series of laws and measures designed to push peasants out of the old
and into the new by destroying their traditional means of self-support.
“The brutal acts associated with the process of stripping
the majority of the people of the means of producing for themselves might seem
far removed from the laissez-faire reputation of classical political economy,”
writes Perelman. “In reality, the dispossession of the majority of small-scale
producers and the construction of laissez-faire are closely connected, so much
so that Marx, or at least his translators, labeled this expropriation of the
masses as ‘‘primitive accumulation.’’
PERELMAN OUTLINES THE MANY DIFFERENT POLICIES THROUGH WHICH
PEASANTS WERE FORCED OFF THE LAND—FROM THE ENACTMENT OF SO-CALLED GAME LAWS
THAT PROHIBITED PEASANTS FROM HUNTING, TO THE DESTRUCTION OF THE PEASANT
PRODUCTIVITY BY FENCING THE COMMONS INTO SMALLER LOTS—BUT BY FAR THE MOST
INTERESTING PARTS OF THE BOOK ARE WHERE YOU GET TO READ ADAM SMITH’S
PROTO-CAPITALIST COLLEAGUES COMPLAINING AND WHINING ABOUT HOW PEASANTS ARE TOO
INDEPENDENT AND COMFORTABLE TO BE PROPERLY EXPLOITED, AND TRYING TO FIGURE OUT
HOW TO FORCE THEM TO ACCEPT A LIFE OF WAGE SLAVERY.
This pamphlet from the time captures the general attitude
towards successful, self-sufficient peasant farmers: THE POSSESSION OF A
BOVINE, OR TWO, WITH A HOG, AND A FEW GEESE, NATURALLY EXALTS THE PEASANT. . .
. IN SAUNTERING AFTER HIS CATTLE, HE ACQUIRES A HABIT OF INDOLENCE. QUARTER,
HALF, AND OCCASIONALLY WHOLE DAYS, ARE IMPERCEPTIBLY LOST. DAY LABOUR BECOMES
DISGUSTING; THE AVERSION IN- CREASES BY INDULGENCE. AND AT LENGTH THE SALE OF A
HALF-FED CALF, OR HOG, FURNISHES THE MEANS OF ADDING INTEMPERANCE TO IDLENESS.
While another pamphleteer wrote: Nor can I conceive a
greater curse upon a body of people, than to be thrown upon a spot of land,
where the productions for subsistence and food were, in great measure,
spontaneous, and the climate required or admitted little care for raiment or
covering.
JOHN BELLERS, A QUAKER “PHILANTHROPIST” AND ECONOMIC THINKER
SAW INDEPENDENT PEASANTS AS A HINDRANCE TO HIS PLAN OF FORCING POOR PEOPLE INTO
PRISON-FACTORIES, WHERE THEY WOULD LIVE, WORK AND PRODUCE A PROFIT OF 45% FOR
ARISTOCRATIC OWNERS: “OUR FORESTS AND GREAT COMMONS (MAKE THE POOR THAT ARE
UPON THEM TOO MUCH LIKE THE INDIANS) BEING A HINDRANCE TO INDUSTRY, AND ARE
NURSERIES OF IDLENESS AND INSOLENCE.”
Daniel Defoe, the novelist and trader, noted that in the
Scottish Highlands “people were extremely well furnished with provisions. …
venison exceedingly plentiful, and at all seasons, young or old, which they
kill with their guns whenever they find it.’’
To Thomas Pennant, a botanist, this self-sufficiency was
ruining a perfectly good peasant population: The manners of the native
Highlanders may be expressed in these words: indolent to a high degree, unless
roused to war, or any animating amusement.”
If having a full belly and productive land was the problem,
then the solution to whipping these lazy bums into shape was obvious: kick ‘em
off the land and let em starve.
Arthur Young, a popular writer and economic thinker
respected by John Stuart Mill, wrote in 1771: “everyone but an idiot knows that
the lower classes must be kept poor, or they will never be industrious.” Sir
William Temple, a politician and Jonathan Swift’s boss, agreed, and suggested
that food be taxed as much as possible to prevent the working class from a life
of “sloth and debauchery.”
Temple also advocated putting four-year-old kids to work in
the factories, writing ‘‘for by these means, we hope that the rising generation
will be so habituated to constant employment that it would at length prove
agreeable and entertaining to them.’’ Some thought that four was already too
old. According to Perelmen, “John Locke, often seen as a philosopher of
liberty, called for the commencement of work at the ripe age of three.” Child
labor also excited Defoe, who was joyed at the prospect that “children after
four or five years of age…could every one earn their own bread.’’ But that’s
getting off topic…
Even David Hume, that great humanist, hailed poverty and
hunger as positive experiences for the lower classes, and even blamed the
“poverty” of France on its good weather and fertile soil: “‘Tis always
observed, in years of scarcity, if it be not extreme, that the poor labour
more, and really live better.”
Reverend Joseph Townsend believed that restricting food was
the way to go: “[Direct] legal constraint [to labour] . . . is attended with
too much trouble, violence, and noise, . . . whereas hunger is not only a
peaceable, silent, unremitted pressure, but as the most natural motive to
industry, it calls forth the most powerful exertions. . . . Hunger will tame
the fiercest animals, it will teach decency and civility, obedience and
subjugation to the most brutish, the most obstinate, and the most perverse.”
PATRICK COLQUHOUN, A MERCHANT WHO SET UP ENGLAND’S FIRST
PRIVATE “PREVENTATIVE POLICE“ FORCE TO PREVENT DOCK WORKERS FROM SUPPLEMENTING
THEIR MEAGER WAGES WITH STOLEN GOODS, PROVIDED WHAT MAY BE THE MOST LUCID
EXPLANATION OF HOW HUNGER AND POVERTY CORRELATE TO PRODUCTIVITY AND WEALTH
CREATION: POVERTY IS THAT STATE AND CONDITION IN SOCIETY WHERE THE INDIVIDUAL
HAS NO SURPLUS LABOUR IN STORE, OR, IN OTHER WORDS, NO PROPERTY OR MEANS OF
SUBSISTENCE BUT WHAT IS DERIVED FROM THE CONSTANT EXERCISE OF INDUSTRY IN THE
VARIOUS OCCUPATIONS OF LIFE. POVERTY IS THEREFORE A MOST NECESSARY AND
INDISPENSABLE INGREDIENT IN SOCIETY, WITHOUT WHICH NATIONS AND COMMUNITIES
COULD NOT EXIST IN A STATE OF CIVILIZATION. IT IS THE LOT OF MAN. IT IS THE
SOURCE OF WEALTH, SINCE WITHOUT POVERTY, THERE COULD BE NO LABOUR; THERE COULD
BE NO RICHES, NO REFINEMENT, NO COMFORT, AND NO BENEFIT TO THOSE WHO MAY BE
POSSESSED OF WEALTH.
COLQUHOUN’S SUMMARY IS SO ON THE MONEY, IT HAS TO BE
REPEATED. BECAUSE WHAT WAS TRUE FOR ENGLISH PEASANTS IS STILL JUST AS TRUE FOR
US: “POVERTY IS THEREFORE A MOST NECESSARY AND INDISPENSABLE INGREDIENT IN SOCIETY…IT
IS THE SOURCE OF WEALTH, SINCE WITHOUT POVERTY, THERE COULD BE NO LABOUR; THERE
COULD BE NO RICHES, NO REFINEMENT, NO COMFORT, AND NO BENEFIT TO THOSE WHO MAY
BE POSSESSED OF WEALTH.”
Comments
Post a Comment